Mexico made several reforms in an attempt to bring down fees. One made it easier for investors to switch from one manager to another, but that didn’t do much for fees, as investors weren’t focusing on them anyway.
Another attempted to attack investors’ lack of focus on cost. The government introduced an index intended to allow investors to more easily compare fund managers’ fees. It required that fund managers show a standardized table of comparative fees that boiled loads and asset fees into one more-digestible fee that would make it easier to comparison shop. But investors still bought high-fee funds, according to Brown’s Hastings and RAND Corporation’s Fabian Duarte.
The government required fund managers to show combined load and balance fees according to a formula that was simple to read but, crucially, didn’t reflect true costs. Investors did pay attention to the index, and many did switch their investment choices in an attempt to invest more wisely. However, management companies restructured their fees to exploit the formula. They lowered load fees but raised management fees to maintain a low index value. As a result, many investors ended up in funds that were more expensive than they realized, and managers continued raking in hefty profits.
The new fee structure actually raised management costs for low-wage workers, who ended up subsidizing wealthier workers, according to Hastings and Duarte. “Rather than harnessing perfect competition, privatized social safety net markets may result in abundant advertising or complicated and obfuscated fee schedules,” they write.
Financial-literacy programs for low-income workers would help, according to a model created by Hastings, Hortaçsu, and Syverson. Combining those with a low-cost government alternative that would give the private-fund managers some additional competition could force down prices by as much as 77 percent, the researchers estimate.
“Our study not only helps explain experiences and outcomes in one of the world’s largest privatized social security markets, but also suggests broader lessons as retirement savings and health-insurance markets head toward greater individual control,” Hastings, Hortaçsu, and Syverson write.
Mandated savings in Australia
Mexico’s experience offers one cautionary tale, and Australia’s offers another, although somewhat more hopeful. “Australia’s retirement income system is regarded by some as among the best in the world,” writes Julie Agnew of the College of William and Mary. “It has achieved high individual saving rates and broad coverage at reasonably low cost to the government.”
In 1992, Australia recognized its own retirement savings system was inadequate, and its leaders embraced savings and optional matching employer contributions. It kept a government-funded pension safety net, introduced in 1908, but it also required that almost all workers participate in a retirement savings system. Most plans are privately operated.