But in the following decades, Schumpeter found support in two developments in financial economics that seemed to vindicate the fierce individualism of his hero. The first was the efficient-markets hypothesis, developed by Chicago Booth’s Eugene F. Fama in the late 1960s. The theory holds that, when all participants have the same information available to them, no single investor can consistently earn above-average returns on the market. By implication, the theory cast a negative light on regulatory efforts to intervene in market activities, regardless of the social aims intended, while also giving moral cover to commercial actors who could console themselves with the belief that, by pursuing their private interests, they were best supporting the public welfare. Thanks to the providential wisdom of the invisible hand, their greed, however blinkered, was actually good.
Not long after Fama’s insights began reshaping how people thought about financial markets, Harvard’s Michael Jensen and the late William Meckling attempted to reconceptualize the nature of the modern corporation. Eschewing the more traditional sociological approach that treated companies as small communities shaped by community obligations and a complex series of institutional customs, Jensen and Meckling contended that companies could best be understood as a collection of independent agents bound only by contractual obligations. These individuals were not guided by a vibrant suite of sympathies, sensibilities, and higher aims—community improvement, quality products, the pleasure and purpose of superior craftsmanship. They were corporate mercenaries with the same, singular motivation that propelled the entities they worked for: to make as much money as possible. Accordingly, if companies wanted to ensure their aims were best aligned with those of their agents, they should focus on one type of incentive only, the profit motive.
A flagging interest in finance
As I’ve already noted, for Max Weber, the idea that any single type of incentive might overwhelmingly shape one’s activity could only be the consequence of a “long, slow ‘process of education.’” Yes, the possibility of higher wages can go a long way toward skewing individual behavior—the difference between what one might do for $10 and what he might do for $1 million underscores this—but the mere promise of more and better baubles won’t ensure an unalloyed commitment to moneymaking. And yet, if money is essential not only to meeting material needs but to attaining power, status, opportunities, and self-respect, it doesn’t merely outweigh other interests; it effectively devours them.
As the spirit of renegade capitalism blossomed in the 1970s and ’80s from academic theories that redefined how we understood the very nature of a well-functioning economy, the expanding power of money served as both a carrot and a stick to such development. On the one hand, over the past 40 years, the growth of material rewards for commercial success has been positively eyepopping. (Forbes, for example, identified more than 2,200 billionaires in 2018, up from just 140 in 1987, the year Wall Street was released.) More importantly, though, in the same period of time, nonmaterial goods have increasingly been colored by money. Indeed, in the US, success in moneymaking often seems like a requirement for status, power, opportunity, and self-respect, making it less a single interest among others than the makings of a lifelong obsession.
No one can doubt that money is far more important today than it was 40 years ago, maybe more than it has ever been in American life. And as the customs and institutions of civil society have been renovated to reflect this fact, they have reinforced the essential lesson of contemporary capitalism: that making as much money as you can, in Weberian parlance, is its own calling, one whose wisdom has been certified by economic science.
And yet, things may be changing. The spirit of capitalism always passes along from one generation to the next, and therefore its immediate fate rests in the hands of those who are getting a firm grip on their bootstraps. Consider the evolving career choices of the young professionals who are currently pursuing their MBAs at elite institutions. According to US News & World Report, the percentage of graduates from the top 10 business schools accepting job offers from the financial sector dropped from 35.7 percent in 2012 to 26.4 percent in 2017—even though, during the same time period, companies raised their starting salaries faster than management consulting firms or tech companies, their rivals in recruiting.
Attempting to explain the flagging interest in finance, a career-services advisor at MIT Sloan School of Management told the Wall Street Journal that students were increasingly unwilling to trade off robust social lives for a few more dollars. Noting over the last decade a nearly “complete flip between finance and technology” in the career aspirations of admitted students, she voiced a conviction that I’ve heard repeatedly expressed by my own students: “You can have a lucrative career without those lifestyle costs.”
In the same article, the founder of a Los Angeles–based recruiting company echoed another belief that is familiar from my classes. Financial-sector companies, he told WSJ, “are increasingly seen as ruthless moneymaking machines.” Rather than making for a wholesale endorsement among MBAs, this impression has created a “serious image problem” for major investment banks, limiting their choice of hires.
This is just one data point, but it is not easily dismissed. Among the ranks of business professionals, the graduates of top business schools are a high-profile group whose behavior uniquely embodies the evolving spirit of American capitalism. The shift in their career decisions suggests a change in the way they interpret the moral necessities of their work and, thus, a break from the preceding generation. When it comes to the question that has long been the full measure of business ambition—Can you ever make enough money?—they increasingly answer in the affirmative. Moreover, not only do they seem unconvinced by the idea that every exercise in greed is also self-evidently good; they would rather work in an environment that evaluates their ultimate worth to others, and to the world around them, by some other measure than dollars and cents.
As polls over the last few years have repeatedly shown, among younger Americans, the siren’s song of capitalism is increasingly falling on deaf ears. If the system is to survive in any form—an eventuality that appears less likely than it did a decade ago, when the contrary seemed unthinkable—it will be because the system of capitalism rediscovers democratic endorsement. We are witnessing one reason for optimism in the sentiments of a new generation of strivers who are disdaining an unreflective faith in the virtue of selfish behavior. They no longer accept as axiomatic that doing well is doing good. They hold themselves to a different standard: the immediate evidence of their actions.
John Paul Rollert is adjunct assistant professor of behavioral science at Chicago Booth.