Policy

Why the US should free its immigration policies

By John H. Cochrane     
September 2, 2014

From: Magazine

Stanford University’s Hoover Institution asked me to write an essay for its immigration journal, Peregrine, with the title, “What is the optimal number of immigrants to the US?” 

My answer: 2,002,052,035. Seriously. 

The United States is made up of 3.5 million square miles, with 84 people per square mile. The United Kingdom has 650 people per square mile. If we let in 2 billion people, we’ll have no more population density than the UK. 

Why the UK? Well, it seems like a really pretty country and none too crowded on Masterpiece Theater. The Netherlands is also attractive with 1,250 people per square mile, so maybe 4 billion. Okay, maybe more of the US is uninhabitable desert or tundra, so maybe only 1 billion. However you cut it, the US still looks severely underpopulated relative to many other pleasant, advanced countries. 

As you can see by my playful calculation, asking what is the optimal number of immigrants is the wrong question. 

What is the optimal number of imported tomatoes? Soviet central-planners tried to figure things out this way. Americans shouldn’t. We should decide on the optimal terms on which tomatoes can be imported, and then let the market decide the number. Similarly, we should debate what the optimal terms for immigration are—How will we let people immigrate? What kind of people?—so that the vast majority of such immigrants are a net benefit to the US. Then, let as many come as want to. On the right terms, the number will self-regulate. 

Econ 101: figure out the price, then set the rules of the game; don’t decide the quantity, or determine the outcome. When a society sets target quantities, or sets quotas, as the US does now with immigration, the result is generally a calamitous waste. With an immigrant quota, an entrepreneur who could come to the US and start a billion-dollar business faces the same restriction as everyone else. The potential Albert Einstein or Sergey Brin has no way to signal just how much his contribution to our society would be. 

Why fear immigrants? You might fear they will overuse social services. Morally, just why your taxes should support an unfortunate who happened to be born in Maine and not one who happened to be born in Guadalajara is an interesting question, but leave that aside for now. It’s easy enough to structure a deal that protects the finances of the welfare state. Immigrants would pay a bond at the border, say $5,000. If they run out of money, are convicted of a crime, don’t have health insurance, or whatever, the bond pays for their ticket home. Alternatively, the government could establish an asset and income test: immigrants must show $10,000 in assets and either a job within six months or visible business or asset income. 

In any case, welfare is a red herring. Immigrants might go to France for a welfare state. The vast majority of immigrants to the US come to work, and pay taxes. Overuse of social services is simply not a problem. But if you worry about it, it’s easy to structure the deal. 

You might fear that immigrants will compete for jobs, and drive down American wages. Again, this is not demonstrably a serious problem. If labor does not move in, capital—factories and farms—moves out and wages go down anyway. Immigrants come to work in wide-open industries with lots of jobs, not those where there are few jobs and many workers. Thus, restrictions on immigration do little, in the long run of an open economy such as the US, to “protect” wages. 

To the extent wage-boosting immigration restrictions can work, the higher wages translate into higher prices to American consumers. The country as a whole—especially low-income consumers who tend to shop at Walmart and benefit the most from low-priced goods—is not better off.  

As a concrete example, we keep doctors and nurses out. And we bemoan how expensive health care has become. Well, immigration restrictions are designed to keep American wages up, and there they are, working as promised. But keeping doctor wages up means keeping your health costs up.

Wage-boosting arguments are particularly hypocritical for conservatives. If you recognize the failure of minimum wages, unions, occupational licensing, hours limitations, protectionism against imported goods, and other misguided policies to try to raise the well-being of American workers, then you have no business supporting immigration limits to the same end.  

And finally, if it did work, restricting immigration benefits some American workers by hurting Mexican workers. Is it really America’s place in the world to take opportunities from poor Mexicans to subsidize our workers’ standard of living? We are a strange country that, according to the Equal Employment Opportunity Commission, rigorously prohibits employment discrimination “because of birthplace, ancestry, culture, linguistic characteristics common to a specific ethnic group, or accent . . .” and then requires such discrimination because of, well, birthplace. 

But if that’s a worry, fine. The government could license protected occupations such that only US citizens can hold the protected occupational licenses. Too intrusive? Well, that’s what we’re trying to do by keeping people out, and good policy is not produced by putting nice appearances on nasty policies. 

More seriously, one can worry that our society quickly absorbs educated people: engineers, programmers, venture capitalists, MBAs, and professors, but does not quickly absorb people with less education. If the low-skill, low-assimilation objection has merit, let in anyone with specific skills and credentials. Let’s talk about the terms, not the numbers. 

Maybe you worry about social values. One can easily demand that immigrants speak English, and have a vague understanding of American institutions, history, and law, though we don’t require this of
our native citizens. Fine. Let’s talk about the deal, not the numbers. 

Maybe you worry, how will we build homes and find jobs for all these people? “We” don’t. They will. Markets, not the government, already provide homes and jobs for citizens. And anyway, aren’t we supposed to be worried about our stagnant economy? Everyone wants more housing construction in the US, yet there are only so many people who need only so many houses. Imagine the construction boom from millions of additional immigrants each year. Our ancestors did not need the American Indian federal government to provide them jobs or build them houses. Neither do new immigrants. 

A ridiculous number of talented people are forced to leave after coming to the US to get engineering or business-school diplomas from US universities. Anyone who gets a degree here should be able to stay. Instead, we kick them out. 

Another 11 million people are here, working hard, paying taxes, owning property, but scurrying around in semilegal status. They can’t really sue if swindled. They certainly can’t vote on how the society they live in works. They can’t get a driver’s license. They live in constant fear. This is a national embarrassment. We criticize other nations for “apartheid” when they deny legal status to people who have been living there for decades, or even generations. Yet one in 20 people living within US borders suffers the same fate. 

OK, they are “illegal.” But Jim Crow had the full force of law too. Does, “They should respect the law,” apply to segregation laws?  Not all laws are good. And, “They should get in line and follow the law,” is empty—it is simply impossible for the average migrant from Mexico, China, or India to come legally to the US.

If you’ve been here x years, have a job, and have stayed out of trouble, then you should get to stay. If we let everyone else who wants to migrate on these same terms, then we don’t have to worry about the unfairness of letting illegals “jump the line.” Get the terms right, and there will be no lines and no unfairness. 

Let’s talk about the deal, not the numbers. For every objection to open immigration, it’s easy enough to find terms of the deal to resolve the matter. The right terms will allow the optimal amount of immigration to settle itself, so that no apparatchik in Washington has to come up with a number. Once we get the terms right, every person who can benefit our society will come, and America will truly be a great nation of great immigrants again. 

John H. Cochrane is AQR Capital Management Distinguished Service Professor of Finance and a senior fellow of the Hoover Institution. Previous versions of this essay appeared in Peregrine, and on Cochrane’s blog, The Grumpy Economist.

Works cited

John H. Cochrane, “After the ACA: Freeing the Market for Health Care,” Expanded version of remarks given at “The Future of Health Care Reform in the United States” conference, University of Chicago Law School, October 2012. Revised June 2014.

“Facts about National Origin Discrimination,” US Equal Employment Opportunity Commission website (eeoc.gov/eeoc/publications/fs-nator.cfm), Accessed July 2014.

More from the Magazine

An error has occurred

An error has occurred